100% satisfaction guarantee Immediately available after payment Both online and in PDF No strings attached
logo-home
Summary of Micro econometrics 2023 $14.05
Add to cart

Summary

Summary of Micro econometrics 2023

 17 views  0 purchase
  • Course
  • Institution

This document includes summaries of all the lecture slides and papers discussed in the course Microeconometrics 2023 at the UvA. The following papers are included: Marshall & Pires (2018), Kools & Knoef (2019), Myers & Lanahan (2022), Hussinger (2008), Garlick & Hyman (2022), Moschion & van Ours (2...

[Show more]

Preview 3 out of 61  pages

  • March 21, 2023
  • 61
  • 2022/2023
  • Summary
avatar-seller
Theory 1
Binary choice models: 𝑦𝑖 can take two values (usually 0 or 1)

- OLS (Linear Probability Model (LPM))
- Logit model
- Probit model
Linear probability model: 𝑃(𝑦𝑖 = 1|𝑥𝑖) = 𝐸[𝑦𝑖 |𝑥𝑖 ] = 𝑥𝑖'β

- Use OLS to estimate
- Problems: probability is not restricted to [0,1] and there is heteroskedasticity
(standard errors of variable are not constant)
Logit and Probit model: 𝑃(𝑦𝑖 = 1|𝑥𝑖) = 𝐹( 𝑥𝑖'β) and 𝑃(𝑦𝑖 = 0|𝑥𝑖) = 1 − 𝐹( 𝑥𝑖'β)

- Logit: 𝐹 = logistic distribution
- Probit: 𝐹 = standard normal distribution
- These models are fully parametric
- Use maximum likelihood to estimate: consistent but you should use robust standard
errors
δ𝑃(𝑦𝑖=1|𝑥𝑖) δ𝐹( 𝑥𝑖'β)
- δ𝑥𝑖𝑗
= δ𝑥𝑖'β
β𝑗 : effect of x on the probability depends on the observation i and

the direction of the effect is determined by β𝑗

Alternative models:
- Latent variables model
- Random utility model
* *
Latent variable model: 𝑦𝑖 = 𝑥𝑖'β + ϵ𝑖 then 𝑦𝑖 = 1 if 𝑦𝑖 ≥ 0 so 𝑃(𝑦𝑖 = 1|𝑥𝑖) = 𝑃(ϵ𝑖 ≥ − 𝑥𝑖'β)
*
Panel data: 𝑦𝑖𝑡 = 𝑥𝑖𝑡'β + α𝑖 + λ𝑡 + ϵ𝑖𝑡

- Random effects: no problem but we have to decide on a distribution
- Fixed effects: α𝑖 can be removed in Logit model (but not efficient) and λ𝑡 can be

removed by using time dummies (LSDV) but this doesn’t work
Multinomial choice: 𝑦𝑖 = 𝑗 for j =1,2,...,M

- Bivariate logit and probit models can be generalized
𝑒𝑥𝑝(𝑥𝑖'β𝑗 +γ'𝑧𝑖𝑗+𝑤𝑗'α𝑖)
Multivariate logit: 𝑃(𝑦𝑖𝑗 = 1 | 𝑥𝑖, 𝑧𝑖𝑗, 𝑤𝑗 ) = 𝑀
∑ 𝑒𝑥𝑝(𝑥𝑖'β𝑗 +γ'𝑧𝑖𝑗+𝑤𝑗'α𝑖)
𝑗=1


- 𝑤𝑗 is never present, so we assume α𝑖 = 0

- If γ = 0: Multinomial Logit Model (MNL): only observation specific regressors ->
normalization needed & estimated by maximum likelihood

, - if β𝑗 = 0 for all j: Conditional Logit Model: only observation and alternative specific

regressors -> no normalization needed
- Mixed logit: combination of the above
Revealed vs stated preference data:
- Revealed preference: observe actual choices made: less reliable because
retrospective
- Stated preference: indicate the preferred alternative: less reliable because no actual
choice has been made
Additive Random Utility Models (ARUM): 𝑈𝑖𝑗 = 𝑉𝑖𝑗 + ϵ𝑖𝑗 : errors are split up in a deterministic

part (𝑉𝑖𝑗) and a random part (ϵ𝑖𝑗 )

- If ϵ𝑖𝑗 are independent over i and j and type I extreme value distributed, use

multinomial logit model -> works best for complementary alternatives
- If ϵ𝑖𝑗 are independent over i and multivariate normal distributed, use multinomial probit

model
Nested MNL: tree-structure -> not applied very often


Marhall & Pires (2018)
Introduction
The paper models how consumers (or households, in the paper used interchangeably)
choose where to shop
- Consumers trade off the cost of traveling to different stores and the prices and
product assortment of each store (summarized by the store surplus index)
- Measuring the role of travel costs relative to prices and variety is their main empirical
challenge: in a world without travel frictions, consumers would always choose to shop
at the store offering the greatest surplus to consumers in terms of prices and product
variety, but because of the existence of travel costs this is not a given
With the estimates of their model they measure the extent to which travel costs have an
impact on the surplus earned by consumers (the extent to which travel costs lead consumers
to choose store with higher prices/less variety/both)
Model
Store choice model where consumers trade off the cost of traveling to different stores and
the prices and product assortment of each store
- The prices and product variety of each store are summarized by a measure of
consumer surplus that we call the store surplus index

, - Consumers can place more weight on surplus (i.e. prices and product variety)
relative to convenience when shopping for a larger set of goods/when travel is less
costly
The model captures a sequential decision process for 𝐼 consumers who visit one of the
stores in the set 𝐽𝑠𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑠:

1. Consumer 𝑖 chooses where to shop given two considerations: the need to purchase
𝑋𝑖𝑡 products and a vector of trip-timing characteristics 𝑦𝑖𝑡

- 𝑋𝑖𝑡 : number of items rather than a specific list of products

- Trip-timing characteristics may include e.g. weather conditions, traffic conditions and
the opportunity cost of time of consumer 𝑖 at time 𝑡
2. The consumer chooses which products to purchase given her choice of shopping at
store 𝑘 with product range 𝐽𝑘𝑡 and her need to purchase 𝑋𝑖𝑡 units

- Critique: we don’t know what the choice set of the individuals is: how many
supermarket stores J are there available at time t
Decisions are described in reverse order -> we solve the model by backward induction
So we start with the second step: for each of the 𝑋𝑖𝑡 decisions faced by the consumer, the

consumer chooses the product ℎ that maximizes their indirect utility -> consumer 𝑖 chooses
product ℎ when making choice 𝑗 at store 𝑘 if and only if
ℎ 𝑙
𝑢𝑖ℎ𝑘𝑡 =− α𝑝ℎ𝑘𝑡 + ξℎ𝑘𝑡 + ϵ𝑖𝑗𝑡 ≥ 𝑢𝑖𝑙𝑘𝑡 =− α𝑝𝑙𝑘𝑡 + ξ𝑙𝑘𝑡 + ϵ𝑖𝑗𝑡

- α: marginal utility of income
- 𝑝ℎ𝑘𝑡: price of product h at store k at time t

- ξℎ𝑘𝑡 : captures unobserved product-specific characteristics that may vary over time

and across stores

- ϵ𝑖𝑗𝑡 : idiosyncratic taste shock of product h that corresponds to decision number j for

person i at time t -> while consumers face the same observable product
characteristics for each of the 𝑋𝑖𝑡 product choices, the randomness of the unobserved

taste shocks generates variation in the outcome of each of the 𝑋𝑖𝑡 product choices

- Later on they use notation ϵ𝑖ℎ𝑗𝑡 instead of ϵ𝑖𝑗𝑡

Mistake: the indirect utility function 𝑢𝑖ℎ𝑘𝑡 =− α𝑝ℎ𝑘𝑡 + ξℎ𝑘𝑡 + ϵℎ𝑖𝑗𝑡 = 𝑉ℎ𝑘𝑡 + ϵℎ𝑖𝑗𝑡 is not actually

an indirect utility function because it does not include the income of the consumer

The benefits of buying summaries with Stuvia:

Guaranteed quality through customer reviews

Guaranteed quality through customer reviews

Stuvia customers have reviewed more than 700,000 summaries. This how you know that you are buying the best documents.

Quick and easy check-out

Quick and easy check-out

You can quickly pay through credit card or Stuvia-credit for the summaries. There is no membership needed.

Focus on what matters

Focus on what matters

Your fellow students write the study notes themselves, which is why the documents are always reliable and up-to-date. This ensures you quickly get to the core!

Frequently asked questions

What do I get when I buy this document?

You get a PDF, available immediately after your purchase. The purchased document is accessible anytime, anywhere and indefinitely through your profile.

Satisfaction guarantee: how does it work?

Our satisfaction guarantee ensures that you always find a study document that suits you well. You fill out a form, and our customer service team takes care of the rest.

Who am I buying these notes from?

Stuvia is a marketplace, so you are not buying this document from us, but from seller studentuva2023. Stuvia facilitates payment to the seller.

Will I be stuck with a subscription?

No, you only buy these notes for $14.05. You're not tied to anything after your purchase.

Can Stuvia be trusted?

4.6 stars on Google & Trustpilot (+1000 reviews)

56326 documents were sold in the last 30 days

Founded in 2010, the go-to place to buy study notes for 14 years now

Start selling
$14.05
  • (0)
Add to cart
Added