100% satisfaction guarantee Immediately available after payment Both online and in PDF No strings attached
logo-home
Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus, Perloff - Downloadable Solutions Manual (Revised) $28.48   Add to cart

Exam (elaborations)

Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus, Perloff - Downloadable Solutions Manual (Revised)

2 reviews
 387 views  4 purchases

Description: Solutions Manual for Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus, Perloff, 5e is all you need if you are in need for a manual that solves all the exercises and problems within your textbook. Answers have been verified by highly experienced instructors who teaches courses a...

[Show more]

Preview 4 out of 480  pages

  • July 1, 2022
  • 480
  • 2021/2022
  • Exam (elaborations)
  • Questions & answers
book image

Book Title:

Author(s):

  • Edition:
  • ISBN:
  • Edition:
All documents for this subject (4)

2  reviews

review-writer-avatar

By: robinschuurman • 9 months ago

review-writer-avatar

By: stijngoedvolk • 1 year ago

avatar-seller
tb4u
Chapter 1 Introduction ◼ Chapter Outline 1.1 Microeconomics: The Allocation of Scarce Resources Trade -Offs Which goods and services to produce. How to produce. Who gets the goods and services? Who Makes the Decisions? How Prices Determine Allocations Application: Twinkie Tax 1.2 Models Application: Income Threshold Model and China Simplifications by Assumption Testing Theories Maximizing Subject to Constraints Positive Versus Normative 1.3 Uses of Microeconomic Models ◼ Teaching Tips You might begin the first class by discussing with the students the role of the intermediate microeconomics class in the larger curriculum. Encourage the students to be interactive by asking questions, bringing in examples from the newspaper, and questioning concepts that seem untrue or unrealistic. For many professors, a primary goal of the course is to get students to think like economists. The material in Chapter 1 should help the students to understand what is required to do. You might want to ask your students the policy questions listed below as a kind of pretest. Simply ask them to write down the best answer they can for now, and then put their answers away. You can then return to these answers later in the semester. Some suggested policy questions (be sure to ask only questions that you will address later in the course): 1. How do minimum wages affect wages, employment, and unemployment? 2. Is the consumer price index (CPI) a good measure of inflation? 3. Why do stores offer coupons instead of simply reducing the price by the value of the coupon? 4. How do taxes affect consumers and businesses? 5. Why do some workers prefer set wages rather than commissions, even if they might make more working on commission? 6. Agree or disag ree: We should strive to be a zero pollution society. On a more pragmatic level, I stress to the students that success in the class is heavily dependent on their approach to the material. Specifically, I emphasize that memorization is an extremely ineffect ive tool for studying economics and that students who memorize material are very prone to confusion and “drawing a blank” on exams. I try to persuade them that a much better approach is to press for understanding. I also stress that understanding usually comes only through active engagement with the material, both in class and out. The problems in the text, as well as the additional problems available in this manual and the Study Guide, will benefit the students in this regard. The conceptual and technical questions throughout these problem sets are designed to facilitate student understanding. I also emphasize the importance of coming to class regularly. Paul Romer’s article, “Do Students Go to Class? Should They?” in the Journal of Economic Perspectives (vol. 7, no. 3, Summer 1993:167 –74) shows that perfect class attendance is worth between one and two grade points, and attendance at all rather than half of classes is worth between 0.67 and 1.24 grade points. Referring to this evidence might add some weigh t to your argument. Finally, I recommend that all students bring a protractor and a few colored pencils to class to aid their note taking. One of the most frequent problems for students who are struggling is sloppy lecture notes. A protractor is great for drawing lines and curves and has the added benefit of being transparent. Colored pencils are a big help when students are taking notes on graphs with many different lines, such as income and substitution effects and long - and short -run cost. Chapter 1 serv es as an introduction to the text as well as a refresher of some basic economic concepts and definitions. This is a good chapter to get started, during the first day, as most students wouldn’t have read it before class. It will give you the opportunity to get an idea of the students’ memory on these basic concepts. I usually start by asking the class for a definition of economics. If you get several suggestions that do not include the concept of scarcity, consider writing them on the board. Ask the class if they can think of what central idea is missing from the definitions given. The discussion of scarcity and the questions of what, how, and for whom to produce should lead you directly into a discussion of the role of prices as an allocation mechanism. In the discussion of prices and markets, I try to get the students to offer examples from recent events where prices have risen or fallen sharply (a good current example is oil prices). Another possibility is to ask the students why some prices are so high (e .g., diamonds) and others are so low (water, to start on that classic paradox). Ideally, you will end up in a discussion of the ways in which supply and demand interact to allocate resources. I also like to talk briefly about market failure and why the Uni ted States is a mixed economy rather than a pure market economy. The Twinkie tax application is a good example for discussion purposes. When discussing allocation of goods and services, an effective counterpoint to the market system is consideration of the centrally planned economy. Examples can include China’s version of central planning, as well as Cuba and North Korea. Many students have very little knowledge of how centrally planned economies operate, the difficulties they face in meeting the demands o f their citizens, and how these difficulties relate to the current political changes. The discussion of economic models is very important. Most students do not have a sound understanding of the construction and purpose of an economic model. Stress the poin t that economic models are allegories used to describe behaviors and outcomes that would otherwise be unnecessarily complicated. Rather than try to duplicate the actual phenomenon, economists use models to make predictions about the behavior of firms and i ndividuals. Perhaps the most important point to make regarding models is that they are simplified through the use of assumptions. You might choose a typical market and describe the wide variety of complex interactions that would have to be quantified in or der to produce a complete model. Then describe the circumstances under which a very simple economic model can make satisfactory predictions (where “satisfactory” can be defined a number of ways, such as the coefficient of determination in a regression mode l). You may also want to discuss interactions that are too difficult to model and why. For example, modeling behavior in unstable political climates is difficult because of the large influence of events that cannot be forecast. Finally, you might discuss t he use of models to test theories and make predictions. Often students have a somewhat jaded view of economists and their predictions. I like to point out that although predictions often turn out to be incorrect, the error can frequently be traced to incor rect assumptions made at the time of the prediction. For example, suppose a forecasting model is constructed to predict baseball game attendance. Assuming a bright sunny day, attendance at a baseball game is predicted to be 40,000. If only 10,000 fans show up on game day, it could be that the model is bad, but it could also be that the weather is cool with a steady rain. In this case, the assumption, not the model, was flawed. Chapter 1 also introduces the difference between positive and normative economics. It does not take long to cover, and a brief discussion of this point is worth the time. You might begin by asking students the distinction between positive and normative pro blems. I often find that students either do not know at all or are very unsure about their responses. To get the class thinking, use current societal problems as discussion points. Ask the class what would be a fair price for an Ebola vaccine. The variety of responses shows the normative nature of the question, but there is no disagreement that the vaccine should be produced in the least costly way possible, regardless of how the gains are shared. Note that most problems have both positive and normative asp ects and that by separating objective issues from subjective ones, we can more easily understand and approach the problems and find effective solutions. The text example of the wisdom of food price controls in Africa during droughts makes this point well. When covering Section 1.3 (Uses of Microeconomic Models), you might discuss the effect of subprime mortgages on the housing market, or draw on examples from current events that require the use of models. I like to draw the distinction between structural mo dels that may be used, for example, to determine an elasticity, and forecasting models that emphasize predictive power over theoretical correctness. If the students’ backgrounds in statistics are weak, you may have to keep this discussion at a broad concep tual level. This section provides a great opportunity to make the subject matter come alive for the students. This text is designed to be used in courses where calculus is a prerequisite. I find that, even though students have all taken calculus, they don’ t remember much of it. I find it useful to spend some time reviewing the rules of algebra and the basics of calculus. Also, it is necessary to be able to take partial derivatives, and these are rarely covered in the introductory calculus course.

The benefits of buying summaries with Stuvia:

Guaranteed quality through customer reviews

Guaranteed quality through customer reviews

Stuvia customers have reviewed more than 700,000 summaries. This how you know that you are buying the best documents.

Quick and easy check-out

Quick and easy check-out

You can quickly pay through credit card or Stuvia-credit for the summaries. There is no membership needed.

Focus on what matters

Focus on what matters

Your fellow students write the study notes themselves, which is why the documents are always reliable and up-to-date. This ensures you quickly get to the core!

Frequently asked questions

What do I get when I buy this document?

You get a PDF, available immediately after your purchase. The purchased document is accessible anytime, anywhere and indefinitely through your profile.

Satisfaction guarantee: how does it work?

Our satisfaction guarantee ensures that you always find a study document that suits you well. You fill out a form, and our customer service team takes care of the rest.

Who am I buying these notes from?

Stuvia is a marketplace, so you are not buying this document from us, but from seller tb4u. Stuvia facilitates payment to the seller.

Will I be stuck with a subscription?

No, you only buy these notes for $28.48. You're not tied to anything after your purchase.

Can Stuvia be trusted?

4.6 stars on Google & Trustpilot (+1000 reviews)

75759 documents were sold in the last 30 days

Founded in 2010, the go-to place to buy study notes for 14 years now

Start selling
$28.48  4x  sold
  • (2)
  Add to cart