These notes were prepared based on the lectures and supplemented by information from textbooks and tutorials where parts of the lecture were unclear. Graphs, equations, and bullet-point explanations included. Prepared by a first class Economics and Management student for the FHS Microeconomics pape...
MT7 Information Economics
Lecture 18: Adverse Selection and Screening
Outline:
Introduction
Adverse Selection
Insurance
Screening in insurance
Introduction
General equilibrium theory (1960s-1970s)
o If economic agents are rational (roughly: complete, transitive & continuous preferences,
ideally convex too), all market participants are non-strategic (price taker) and fully
informed, and all goods are traded (no externalities), then the market equilibrium is
efficient.
o Interventions, regulation cause distortions and efficiency loss
Government re-allocates for equity not efficiency purposes. Best to have lump-
sum approaches to minimise efficiency loss
Microeconomics since the 1980s: identify and propose 'fix' to market failures
o Failure of price taking: monopoly theory, Cournot and Bertrand oligopolies, other game-
theoretic models of imperfect competition
Fix: make markets contestable, or regulate natural monopolies
o Externalities: over- (respectively under-) production of negative (respectively positive)
externalities, missing public goods
Fix: create more markets (Coase), quantity v price regulation; mechanisms for
the public or private provision of public goods
o Asymmetric information: adverse selection and moral hazard
This week's content
Adverse selection
Agents in certain markets are heterogeneous: some “good” (highly productive), some “bad”
Agents privately know their Nature-given quality (type)
Adverse selection occurs when the wrong type of agent may make (offer or accept) a deal.
o Trade, or even an offer, may be bad news to one of the parties.
o Marx’s Maxim: I won’t belong to a club that will have me as a member”
Examples:
o Loan offered by bank may be accepted by high-risk borrowers who privately know that
they are unlikely to make payment
o Job offered by a firm at a wage equal to average productivity may be accepted by
below-average productivity workers
o Seller may offer used durable good (e.g., car) for sale only if its privately-known quality
is below average
o Individuals who know that they are careless or accident-prone may be more likely to
seek insurance
Goals of our analysis
, o Study the consequences, testable predictions of adverse selection
o Understand market solutions and develop guidelines for government intervention in
real-life situations
Akerlof’s market for lemons
Insight: adverse selection can shut markets
His model of the market for used cars, in words:
o the owner of a car has private information about its quality
o potential buyers realize this and may be reluctant to purchase for fear of buying a
“lemon”
o vicious circle: buyers are not willing to pay high price, at which sellers are not offering
good quality cars, and so on
o thin market for used cars; the market may even collapse
Numerical example
o The quality of a used car, q, is a random draw between 0 and 1, uniformly distributed
Pr[q ≤ x] = x
E[q|q ≤ x] = ½x
o The seller’s valuation for her car is its quality, q
o The buyer’s valuation for the same car is 1.5 × q (i.e., 50% more)
If there was perfect information trade would occur
o Only the seller knows q
o Both sides are price taker and risk neutral
o There is no trade that occurs
At price p ∈ [0, 1.5] sellers with cars of quality q ≤ p offer to sell
p ∈ [0, 1.5]: theoretically the maximum price buyers are willing to pay is
1.5 for cars q = 1 under perfect information
Buyers infer the average quality of used cars is E[q|q ≤ p] = ½p
Hence a buyer’s willingness to pay for an average used car is 1.5 × ½p = ¾p,
Since WTP < p, buyers will refuse to buy
There is no trade: the market unravels
o Cause: when an individual decides to sell a low-quality car, he affects the purchasers'
perceptions of the quality of the average car on the market
Subtleties: partial unravelling & multiple equilibria
Adverse selection does not necessarily cause a market to fully unravel and no trade to occur.
There can be partial unravelling of the market that produces multiple equilibria.
New example: assume three quality levels H = 100, M = 60, L = 20
o Seller’s valuation is q ∈ {H, M, L}; buyer’s is 50% more
o Seller knows q, buyer does not
o Assume Pr[H] = ½, Pr[M] = Pr[L] = ¼
o Assume that the seller, if indifferent, sells; the buyer, if indifferent, buys.
o Buyer is risk neutral (so we can just take WTP = EV*1.5)
There exists an equilibrium at p ∈ [100, 105], all q levels traded
o At p ≥ 100 all goods are supplied by sellers, since it is above their valuation
, o Since all goods are supplied, E[q] = ½*100 + ¼*60 + ¼*20 = 70
o Buyers’ WTP is 1.5 × 70 = 105
o If buyer's WTP ≥ p (105 ≥ p), they are happy to buy
Another equilibrium at p = 60 with q = L, M traded
o At p = 60, sellers supply L and M
o E[q|q ≤ p = 60] = ½*60 + ½*20 = 40
o Buyers’ WTP is 1.5 × 40 = 60 (buyers willing to buy only if 60 ≥ p)
o Hence, at p =60, sellers supply L and M, while buyers are willing to buy
Third set of equilibria at p ∈ [20, 30], only q = L traded
o At p ≤ 20, seller supplies L
o E[q|q ≤ p = 20] = 20
o Buyers’ WTP is 1.5 × 20 = 30 (buyers willing to buy only if 30 ≥ p)
o Hence, at p ∈ [20, 30], q = L is traded
Adverse selection FAQ
Does adverse selection always start at the top of the quality ladder? (Higher quality products
leave the market supply)
o Yes, if quality is ordered the same way with differing valuations
Who sets the market price?
o Nobody (or, if you like, the mythical “Walrasian auctioneer”)
o We ask, “what type of trades occur at a given price?”
o Need to manually check various price ranges: who sells, who buys
Any guidance on equilibrium price within a given range?
o If there are more sellers than buyers in the market, then presumably, they drive the
price to the bottom of the range
o If buyers outnumber sellers (at a given price) then vice versa
Quality choice
Unlike the lemons model, we consider a variation of the model where quality may be
determined by the producers.
If consumers value high-quality product at $14 and low-quality product at $8, and both the high-
and low-quality products costs producers $11.50. 3 possible cases:
o Only low-quality produced: no product sold, since cost of $11.50 > consumer WTP $8
o Only high-quality produced: product price is $11.50 due to competition, but consumer
WTP is $14, so there is consumer surplus. This is the socially optimal outcome/
o Both qualities produced (at least 7/12 is high-quality): 14q + 8(1-q) ≥ 11.5 (WTP > cost),
so 7/12 ≤ q ≤ 1
Same consumer WTP, but high-quality product costs $11.50 and low-quality product costs $11
o Each producer behaves competitively and believes that choosing to produce high/ low
quality has negligible effects on market price and perceived quality.
o All producers thus select the low-quality product, which means consumer WTP is $8 and
equilibrium is where no products are sold.
Adverse selection in insurance
The benefits of buying summaries with Stuvia:
Guaranteed quality through customer reviews
Stuvia customers have reviewed more than 700,000 summaries. This how you know that you are buying the best documents.
Quick and easy check-out
You can quickly pay through credit card or Stuvia-credit for the summaries. There is no membership needed.
Focus on what matters
Your fellow students write the study notes themselves, which is why the documents are always reliable and up-to-date. This ensures you quickly get to the core!
Frequently asked questions
What do I get when I buy this document?
You get a PDF, available immediately after your purchase. The purchased document is accessible anytime, anywhere and indefinitely through your profile.
Satisfaction guarantee: how does it work?
Our satisfaction guarantee ensures that you always find a study document that suits you well. You fill out a form, and our customer service team takes care of the rest.
Who am I buying these notes from?
Stuvia is a marketplace, so you are not buying this document from us, but from seller ib45pointer. Stuvia facilitates payment to the seller.
Will I be stuck with a subscription?
No, you only buy these notes for $7.39. You're not tied to anything after your purchase.