100% satisfaction guarantee Immediately available after payment Both online and in PDF No strings attached
logo-home
Solutions Manual For Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles and Extensions 12th Edition By Walter Nicholson, Christopher Snyder (All Chapters, 100% Original Verified, A+ Grade) $28.49   Add to cart

Exam (elaborations)

Solutions Manual For Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles and Extensions 12th Edition By Walter Nicholson, Christopher Snyder (All Chapters, 100% Original Verified, A+ Grade)

 15 views  0 purchase
  • Course
  • Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles and Extensio
  • Institution
  • Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles And Extensio

This Is The Original 12th Edition Of The Solution Manual From The Original Author All Other Files In The Market Are Fake/Old Editions. Other Sellers Have Changed The Old Edition Number To The New But The Solution Manual Is An Old Edition. Solutions Manual For Microeconomic Theory Basic Principl...

[Show more]

Preview 4 out of 466  pages

  • September 6, 2024
  • 466
  • 2024/2025
  • Exam (elaborations)
  • Questions & answers
  • Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles and Extensio
  • Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles and Extensio
avatar-seller
studentsupport96
Microeconomic Theory:
Basic Principles and Extensions
12th Edition


Solutions Manual


By

Walter Nicholson & Christopher Snyder

, CHAPTER 2:
Mathematics for Microeconomics
The problems in this chapter are primarily mathematical. They are intended to give students
some practice with the concepts introduced in Chapter 2, but the problems in themselves offer
few economic insights. Consequently, no commentary is provided. Results from some of the
analytical problems are used in later chapters, however, and in those cases the student will be
directed back to this chapter.



Solutions

2.1 f ( x, y ) = 4 x 2 + 3 y 2 .

a. f x = 8 x, f y = 6 y.

b. Constraining f ( x, y ) = 16 creates an implicit function between the variables. The
dy f −8 x
slope of this function is given by =− x = for combinations of x and y
dx fy 6y
that satisfy the constraint.

dy 8 1 2
c. Since f (1, 2) = 16 , we know that at this point =− =− .
dx 62 3

d. The f ( x, y ) = 16 contour line is an ellipse centered at the origin. The slope of the
line at any point is given by dy dx = − 8 x 6 y . Notice that this slope becomes
more negative as x increases and y decreases.


2.2 a. Profits are given by  = R − C = −2q 2 + 40q − 100. The maximum value is found
by setting the derivative equal to 0:
d
= − 4q + 40 = 0 ,
dq
implies q* = 10 and  * = 100.

Since d 2 dq = − 4  0, this is a global maximum.
2
b.

c. MR = dR dq = 70 − 2q. MC = dC dq = 2q + 30. So, q* = 10 obeys
MR = MC = 50.

,2 Chapter 2: Mathematics for Microeconomics


2.3 First, use the substitution method. Substituting y = 1 − x yields
f ( x) = f ( x,1 − x) = x(1 − x) = x − x 2 . Taking the first-order condition, f  ( x) = 1 − 2 x = 0,
and solving yields x* = 0.5, y * = 0.5 , and f ( x* ) = f ( x* , y* ) = 0.25. Since
f ( x* ) = −2  0, this is a local and global maximum.
Next, use the Lagrange method. The Lagrangian is L = xy +  (1 − x − y ). The
first-order conditions are
Lx = y −  = 0,
L y = x −  = 0,
L = 1 − x − y = 0.
Solving simultaneously, x = y. Using the constraint gives x* = y* = 0.5,  = 0.5, and
x* y* = 0.25.


2.4 Setting up the Lagrangian, L = x + y +  (0.25 − xy ). The first-order conditions are
Lx = 1 −  y ,
L y = 1 −  x,
L = 0.25 − xy = 0.
So x = y. Using the constraint ( xy = x 2 = 0.25) gives x* = y* = 0.5 and  = 2. Note that
the solution is the same here as in Problem 2.3, but here the value for the Lagrangian
multiplier is the reciprocal of the value in Problem 2.3.


2.5 a. The height of the ball is given by f (t ) = −0.5 gt 2 + 40t. The value of t for which
height is maximized is found by using the first-order condition: df dt = − gt + 40 = 0, implying
t * = 40 g .

b. Substituting for t * ,
2
 40   40  800
f (t ) = −0.5 g   + 40   =
*
.
 g   g  g
Hence,
df (t * ) 800
=− 2 .
dg g

c. Differentiation of the original function at its optimal value yields
df (t * )
= −0.5(t * ) 2 .
dg
Because the optimal value of t depends on g ,

, Chapter 2: Mathematics for Microeconomics 3


2
df (t * )  40  −800
= − 0.5(t * )2 = −0.5   = 2 ,
dg  g  g
as was also shown in part (c).

d. If g = 32, t * = 5 4. Maximum height is 800 32 = 25. If g = 32.1, maximum
height is 800 32.1 = 24.92, a reduction of 0.08. This could have been predicted
from the envelope theorem, since
 −800   −25 
df (t * ) =  2  dg =   (0.01)  −0.08.
 32   32 


2.6 a. This is the volume of a rectangular solid made from a piece of metal, which is x
by 3x with the defined corner squares removed.

b. The first-order condition for maximum volume is given by
V
= 3x 2 − 16 xt + 12t 2 = 0.
t
Applying the quadratic formula to this expression yields
16 x  256 x 2 − 144 x 2 16 x  10.6 x
t= = = 0.225 x.
24 24
The second value given by the quadratic (1.11x) is obviously extraneous.

c. If t = 0.225 x, V  0.67 x 3 − 0.04 x 3 + 0.05 x 3  0.68 x 3 .
So volume increases without limit.

d. This would require a solution using the Lagrangian method. The optimal solution
requires solving three nonlinear simultaneous equations, a task not undertaken
here. But it seems clear that the solution would involve a different relationship
between t and x than in parts (a–c).

2.7 a. Set up the Lagrangian: L = x1 + 5ln x2 +  (k − x1 − x2 ). The first-
order conditions are
Lx1 = 1 −  = 0,
5
Lx2 = −  = 0,
x2
L = k − x1 − x2 = 0.
Hence,  = 1 = 5 x2 . With k = 10, the optimal solution is x1* = x2* = 5.

b. With k = 4, solving the first-order conditions yields x1* = −1 and x2* = 5.

The benefits of buying summaries with Stuvia:

Guaranteed quality through customer reviews

Guaranteed quality through customer reviews

Stuvia customers have reviewed more than 700,000 summaries. This how you know that you are buying the best documents.

Quick and easy check-out

Quick and easy check-out

You can quickly pay through credit card or Stuvia-credit for the summaries. There is no membership needed.

Focus on what matters

Focus on what matters

Your fellow students write the study notes themselves, which is why the documents are always reliable and up-to-date. This ensures you quickly get to the core!

Frequently asked questions

What do I get when I buy this document?

You get a PDF, available immediately after your purchase. The purchased document is accessible anytime, anywhere and indefinitely through your profile.

Satisfaction guarantee: how does it work?

Our satisfaction guarantee ensures that you always find a study document that suits you well. You fill out a form, and our customer service team takes care of the rest.

Who am I buying these notes from?

Stuvia is a marketplace, so you are not buying this document from us, but from seller studentsupport96. Stuvia facilitates payment to the seller.

Will I be stuck with a subscription?

No, you only buy these notes for $28.49. You're not tied to anything after your purchase.

Can Stuvia be trusted?

4.6 stars on Google & Trustpilot (+1000 reviews)

78075 documents were sold in the last 30 days

Founded in 2010, the go-to place to buy study notes for 14 years now

Start selling
$28.49
  • (0)
  Add to cart