100% tevredenheidsgarantie Direct beschikbaar na betaling Zowel online als in PDF Je zit nergens aan vast
logo-home
Managerial Economics Samenvatting - Handelsingenieur & TEW - 16/20 eerste zit €8,00   In winkelwagen

Samenvatting

Managerial Economics Samenvatting - Handelsingenieur & TEW - 16/20 eerste zit

10 beoordelingen
 873 keer bekeken  86 keer verkocht

Deze samenvatting omvat alle leerstof uit de lessen Managerial Economics, gegeven aan de tweedejaars studenten Handelsingenieur en Toegepaste Economische Wetenschappen (TEW) door Mattia Nardotto en Christophe Crombez. Ik scoorde met deze samenvatting een 16/20 in mijn eerste zit. Deze samenvatting ...

[Meer zien]

Voorbeeld 6 van de 37  pagina's

  • Ja
  • 22 augustus 2021
  • 37
  • 2020/2021
  • Samenvatting
book image

Titel boek:

Auteur(s):

  • Uitgave:
  • ISBN:
  • Druk:
Alle documenten voor dit vak (5)

10  beoordelingen

review-writer-avatar

Door: basilevanhaelst • 1 maand geleden

review-writer-avatar

Door: torbendeveuster • 1 jaar geleden

reply-writer-avatar

Door: simkuhn • 1 jaar geleden

Vertaald door Google

Pipo

review-writer-avatar

Door: tibeaulodewijckx • 1 jaar geleden

review-writer-avatar

Door: charlottedewitte1 • 2 jaar geleden

review-writer-avatar

Door: mosegeg • 2 jaar geleden

review-writer-avatar

Door: arthur_vanderlinden • 2 jaar geleden

review-writer-avatar

Door: sofievandeneede • 1 jaar geleden

Bekijk meer beoordelingen  
avatar-seller
simkuhn
MANAGERIAL‌‌ECONOMICS‌ ‌
Simon‌‌Kuhn‌‌ ‌

LECTURE‌‌1:‌‌FOUNDATIONS‌ ‌
PART‌‌ONE‌ ‌

WHAT‌‌IS‌‌INDUSTRIAL‌‌ORGANISATION?‌‌ ‌
Industrial‌‌Organisation‌‌i‌s‌‌a‌‌branch‌‌of‌‌economics‌‌that‌‌is‌‌concerned‌‌with‌‌the‌‌study‌‌of‌i‌mperfect‌‌
competition‌.‌‌We‌‌will‌‌look‌‌at‌‌ways‌‌for‌‌a‌‌company‌‌to‌‌escape‌‌perfect‌‌competition.‌ ‌
⇒ ‌‌through‌m ‌ arket‌‌power‌:‌ ‌
- innovation‌ ‌
- advertisement‌ ‌
- product‌‌differentiation‌ ‌
- price‌‌discrimination‌ ‌
In‌‌this‌‌course,‌‌we‌‌will‌‌use‌‌managerial‌‌economics‌‌to‌‌answer‌‌practical‌‌questions‌‌on‌‌these‌‌topics.‌ ‌

HOW‌‌WE‌‌STUDY‌‌INDUSTRIAL‌‌ORGANISATION‌ ‌
We‌‌will‌‌make‌‌use‌‌of:‌ ‌
- fundamental‌‌economic‌‌principles‌‌(e.g.‌‌rational‌‌agents,‌‌optimality,...)‌ ‌
- game‌‌theory‌‌because‌‌of‌‌high‌i‌nterdependence‌b ‌ etween‌‌firms‌‌ ‌
- abstract‌‌modeling‌ ‌

THE‌‌PROBLEM‌‌OF‌‌THE‌‌MANAGER‌ ‌
The‌‌Small‌‌Business‌‌Administration‌‌gives‌‌some‌‌basic‌‌guidelines‌‌on‌‌how‌‌to‌‌structure‌‌a‌‌business‌‌plan:‌ ‌
- executive‌‌summary‌‌‌→‌‌the‌‌unique‌‌selling‌‌point,‌‌what‌‌differentiates‌‌the‌‌business‌‌from‌‌others‌ ‌
- company‌‌description‌‌‌→‌‌which‌‌products‌‌and‌‌services,‌‌product‌‌differentiation,...‌ ‌
- market‌‌analysis‌‌‌→‌‌economies‌‌of‌‌scale,‌‌market‌‌concentration,‌‌sunk‌‌costs,...‌ ‌
- service‌‌or‌‌product‌‌line‌→ ‌ ‌‌explain‌‌production‌‌processes,‌‌R&D,‌‌innovation,...‌ ‌
- marketing‌‌and‌‌sales‌→ ‌ ‌‌describe‌‌the‌‌marketing‌‌strategy,‌‌price‌‌discrimination,...‌ ‌
- financial‌‌plan‌‌and‌‌funding‌‌ ‌

All‌‌of‌‌these‌‌elements‌‌have‌‌to‌‌do‌‌with‌‌concepts‌‌studied‌‌in‌‌Managerial‌‌Economics‌.‌ ‌
→‌‌we‌‌will‌‌look‌‌at‌‌the‌‌economics‌‌behind‌‌these‌‌concepts‌‌within‌‌(im)perfect‌‌competition‌‌ ‌
‌in‌‌order‌‌to‌‌use‌‌them‌‌for‌‌more‌‌practical‌‌applications‌‌(e.g.‌‌a‌‌business‌‌plan)‌ ‌

MARKET‌‌DEMAND‌ ‌
In‌‌Managerial‌‌Economics,‌‌we‌‌will‌‌mainly‌‌focus‌‌on‌‌firm‌‌profit-maximizing‌‌behavior‌‌and‌‌a‌‌resultant‌‌market‌‌
outcome‌‌that‌‌such‌‌behavior‌‌implies.‌ ‌

Market‌‌Demand‌‌Curve‌‌d ‌ escribes‌‌the‌‌relationship‌‌between‌‌how‌‌much‌‌money‌‌(aggregated)‌‌consumers‌‌
are‌‌willing‌‌to‌‌pay‌‌per‌‌unit‌‌of‌‌the‌‌good‌‌and‌‌the‌‌quantity‌‌(aggregated)‌‌of‌‌the‌‌goods‌‌consumed.‌ ‌
→‌‌depends‌‌on:‌ ‌
- price‌ ‌
- income‌ ‌
- expectations‌‌of‌‌price‌‌movement...‌ ‌
-⇒ ‌‌Quantity = f (price, income, marketing, ...) ‌

However,‌‌we‌‌will‌‌express‌‌a‌‌simplified‌‌demand‌‌curve‌‌in‌‌terms‌‌of‌‌the‌‌price:‌
1. Q = a bP ‌ −
- a‌‌=‌‌quantity‌‌demanded‌‌when‌‌price‌‌is‌‌very‌‌small‌ ‌
- a/b‌‌=‌‌the‌‌maximum‌‌willingness‌‌to‌‌pay‌ ‌
⇒‌‌this‌‌equation‌‌is‌‌used‌‌when‌‌firms‌‌have‌‌a‌f‌ ixed‌‌quantity‌‌‌but‌‌can‌‌easily‌‌
change‌‌the‌‌price‌‌(e.g.‌‌bakkery)‌‌=‌p ‌ rice-focused‌ ‌


2. P = A B Q (‌ i‌nverse‌)‌ ‌
- A‌‌=‌‌the‌‌maximum‌‌willingness‌‌to‌‌pay‌ ‌
- A/B‌‌=‌‌quantity‌‌demanded‌‌when‌‌price‌‌is‌‌very‌‌small‌ ‌
⇒‌‌this‌‌equation‌‌is‌‌used‌‌when‌‌firms‌‌have‌‌a‌v‌ ariable‌‌quantity‌‌‌(in‌‌extremely‌‌
concentrated‌‌markets‌‌e.g.‌‌oil,‌‌gold,...)‌‌=‌q ‌ uantity-focused‌ ‌


,We‌‌need‌‌to‌‌ask‌‌ourselves‌‌whether‌‌a‌‌linear‌‌market‌‌demand‌‌curve‌‌is‌‌even‌‌realistic?‌ ‌
- it‌‌has‌‌a‌f‌ unctional‌‌form‌‌ ‌
→‌‌closer‌‌to‌‌an‌‌estimation,‌‌yet‌‌fairly‌‌accurate‌‌a‌‌local‌‌level‌ ‌

- it‌‌does‌‌no‌‌take‌‌into‌‌account‌‌the‌t‌ ime‌f‌actor‌ ‌
a. short‌‌run:‌‌no‌‌possibility‌‌to‌‌change‌‌production‌‌facilities‌ ‌
b. long‌‌run:‌‌firm‌‌can‌‌change‌‌its‌‌production‌‌facilities‌‌to‌‌meet‌‌demand‌ ‌
→‌‌but‌‌market‌‌demand‌‌curve‌‌does‌‌not‌‌make‌‌the‌‌distinction,‌‌though‌‌markets‌‌change‌‌constantly‌ ‌

- demand‌‌is‌‌a‌‌function‌‌of‌m ‌ any‌‌aspects‌ ‌
→‌‌income‌‌(cfr.‌‌Engel‌‌Law),‌‌Giffen‌‌goods,‌‌preferences,...‌ ‌

Yet,‌‌despite‌‌its‌‌limitations,‌‌we‌‌will‌‌continue‌‌to‌‌use‌‌the‌‌simple‌‌(inverse)‌‌linear‌‌demand.‌ ‌
→‌‌we‌‌need‌‌to‌‌emphasise‌‌competition,‌‌not‌‌the‌‌demand‌‌curve‌ ‌
→‌‌easy‌‌way‌‌to‌‌find‌‌the‌‌equilibrium‌‌in‌‌any‌‌market‌‌situation‌ ‌

FIRM'S‌‌DEMAND‌ ‌
The‌F ‌ irm's‌‌Demand‌‌g ‌ ives‌‌a‌‌company‌‌an‌‌idea‌‌how‌‌much‌‌they‌‌can‌‌sell,‌‌given‌‌the‌‌price‌‌they‌‌ask:‌ ‌
a. if‌‌there‌‌is‌‌only‌o ⇒
‌ ne‌f‌irm‌‌ ‌‌the‌‌firm's‌‌demand‌‌is‌‌equal‌‌to‌‌the‌‌market‌‌demand‌ ‌
b. if‌‌there‌‌are‌m ⇒
‌ ultiple‌f‌irms‌‌ ‌‌the‌‌firm's‌‌demand‌‌depends‌‌on‌‌other‌‌firms:‌ ‌

‌‌QJ = f (P J , P K , income, marketing J , marketing K , ....) ‌

Firms‌‌have‌‌an‌‌explicit‌‌(e.g.‌‌through‌‌quantitative‌‌market‌‌analysis)‌‌or‌‌implicit‌‌(e.g.‌‌gut-feeling)‌‌of‌‌the‌‌

market‌‌demand,‌‌and‌‌they‌‌try‌‌to‌‌increase‌‌their‌‌firm's‌‌demand‌‌ ‌‌they‌‌need‌‌Managerial‌‌Economics.‌ ‌
→‌‌a‌‌good‌‌understanding‌‌of‌‌the‌‌firm's‌‌demand‌‌is‌‌necessary:‌‌indeed,‌‌we‌‌cannot‌‌start‌‌producing‌‌before‌ ‌
‌we‌‌know‌‌what‌‌we‌‌can‌‌sell.‌ ‌

PRICE‌‌ELASTICITY‌‌OF‌‌DEMAND‌‌ ‌
Elasticity:‌‌ ‌

⇒‌‌ε = ×
Δq
q Δq p Δq Δp
Δp = Δp q
‌‌with‌‌ q = percentage change in q ‌and‌‌ p = percentage change in p ‌
p


- if‌‌|ε| = 1 ⇒‌‌if‌‌price‌‌reduces/increases,‌‌the‌‌quantity‌‌will‌‌reduce/increase‌‌by‌‌the‌‌same‌‌amount‌ ‌
- if‌‌|ε| < 1 ⇒‌‌increasing‌‌price‌‌increases‌‌revenues:‌d‌ emand‌‌is‌‌inelastic‌ ‌
- if‌‌|ε| > 1 ⇒‌‌increasing‌‌price‌‌reduces‌‌revenues:‌d‌ emand‌‌is‌‌elastic‌ ‌

Given‌‌a‌‌demand‌‌curve,‌‌you‌‌would‌‌need‌‌to‌‌find:‌ ‌
Δq dq
- Δp = dp =‌‌the‌‌first‌‌derivative‌‌of‌‌the‌‌Q(p)‌‌function‌ ‌

- p/q =‌‌just‌‌fill‌‌in‌ ‌


Cross-elasticity:‌ ‌

⇒‌‌ε ×
Δq 1
q1 Δq 1 p2
1,2 = Δp2 = Δp2 q1

p2


- if‌‌|| ε1,2 || > 0 ⇒‌s‌ ubstitute‌‌‌goods‌ ‌
- if‌‌|| ε1,2 || < 0 ⇒‌c‌ omplement‌‌‌goods‌ ‌












,PERFECT‌‌COMPETITION‌ ‌
In‌‌perfect‌‌competition,‌‌firms‌‌and‌‌consumers‌‌are‌p ‌ rice-takers‌ ‌
→‌‌there‌‌is‌‌no‌‌market‌‌power,‌‌no‌‌possibility‌‌to‌‌alter‌‌the‌‌price‌ ‌
→‌‌a‌‌firm‌‌can‌‌sell‌‌as‌‌much‌‌or‌‌as‌‌little‌‌as‌‌it‌‌wants‌‌at‌‌the‌‌ruling‌‌market‌‌price‌ ‌
→‌‌the‌‌demand‌‌curve‌‌for‌‌an‌‌individual‌‌firm‌‌is‌‌therefore‌‌a‌‌horizontal‌‌line‌ ‌

Every‌‌player‌‌in‌‌perfect‌‌competition‌‌will,‌‌as‌‌is‌‌normal,‌‌choose‌‌an‌‌output‌‌level‌‌
that‌‌maximises‌‌their‌‌individual‌‌profit.‌ ‌
→‌‌MC‌‌=‌‌MR‌‌and‌‌because‌‌each‌‌product‌‌is‌‌sold‌‌at‌‌the‌‌market‌‌price,‌‌ ‌
M
‌ R‌‌=‌‌P‌‌=‌‌MC‌:‌‌price‌‌therefore‌‌equals‌‌marginal‌‌costs‌‌in‌‌perfect‌‌competition‌ ‌
→‌‌for‌‌every‌‌individual‌‌company,‌‌the‌‌optimal‌‌output‌‌level‌‌q‌‌will‌‌be‌‌summed‌ ‌
‌and‌‌this‌‌gives‌‌us‌‌the‌‌aggregate‌‌output‌‌level‌‌Q‌ ‌

The‌‌market‌‌demand‌‌curve‌‌still‌‌has‌‌a‌‌negative‌‌slope:‌ ‌
→‌‌if‌‌the‌‌entire‌‌market‌‌output‌‌or‌‌price‌‌changes,‌‌the‌‌effect‌‌is‌‌still‌‌noticeable‌‌in‌ ‌
‌the‌‌demand‌‌curve‌ ‌

(graphs‌‌are‌‌for‌o ‌ ne‌‌‌individual‌‌company‌‌left‌‌and‌‌for‌‌the‌e
‌ ntire‌‌‌market‌‌right)‌ ‌

MONOPOLY‌ ‌
If‌‌there‌‌is‌‌only‌‌one‌‌firm‌‌in‌‌the‌‌market,‌‌its‌‌firm's‌‌demand‌‌curve‌‌would‌‌be‌‌identical‌‌to‌‌the‌‌market‌‌demand.‌ ‌
→‌‌it‌‌could‌‌singlehandedly‌‌influence‌‌the‌‌price‌‌as‌‌it‌‌can‌‌singlehandedly‌‌choose‌‌the‌‌supply‌ ‌

As‌‌a‌‌monopolist‌‌has‌‌the‌‌opportunity‌‌to‌‌choose‌‌the‌‌quantity‌‌/‌‌price‌‌as‌‌he‌‌pleases,‌‌he‌‌is‌‌also‌‌
faced‌‌with‌‌a‌‌production‌‌dilemma:‌ ‌

→‌‌producing‌‌ΔQ = Q2 Q1 more‌‌units‌‌increases‌‌revenue‌‌with‌‌G‌ ‌
→‌b −
‌ ut‌‌‌decreased‌‌price‌‌with‌‌ΔP = P 1 P 2 and‌‌thus‌‌revenue‌‌with‌‌L‌ ‌
What‌‌choice‌‌should‌‌the‌‌monopolist‌‌make‌‌if‌‌he‌‌wants‌‌to‌‌maximize‌‌profits?‌ ‌

Like‌‌any‌‌other‌‌firm,‌‌we‌‌need‌‌to‌‌keep‌‌the‌‌optimality‌‌condition‌‌in‌‌mind:‌‌MR‌‌=‌‌MC.‌ ‌
So,‌‌what‌‌is‌‌MR?‌ ‌
× × −
→‌‌T R = q uantity price = Q (A B Q) = AQ B 2 Q ‌ −
⇒ dT R(Q)
‌‌M R = dQ = A 2BQ ‌ −
The‌‌MR-curve‌‌of‌‌a‌‌monopolist‌‌has‌‌the‌‌same‌‌intercept‌‌as‌‌its‌‌demand‌‌curve,‌‌but‌‌twice‌‌the‌‌
slope.‌‌This‌‌means‌‌that‌‌the‌‌MR-curve‌‌will‌‌always‌‌lie‌‌beneath‌‌the‌‌demand‌‌curve.‌ ‌

The‌‌main‌‌difference‌‌between‌‌a‌‌monopolist‌‌and‌‌a‌‌firm‌‌in‌‌perfect‌‌competition‌‌is‌‌that‌ ‌
the‌‌MR‌‌is‌n ‌ ot‌‌equal‌a ‌ nd‌a‌ lways‌‌less‌t‌han‌‌the‌‌actual‌‌market‌‌price.‌‌ ‌

Following‌‌the‌‌optimality‌‌rule,‌‌MC=MR,‌‌the‌‌monopolist‌‌will‌‌product‌‌QM units‌‌ ‌
but‌‌will‌‌sell‌‌them‌‌at‌‌a‌‌clearing‌‌price‌‌of‌‌P M ‌
×
→‌‌the‌‌total‌‌revenue‌‌QM P M ‌is‌‌greater‌‌than‌‌the‌‌total‌‌costs‌‌AC(Q) QM ‌ ×
and‌‌thus‌‌the‌‌monopolist‌‌attains‌‌an‌e ‌ conomic‌‌profit‌.‌ ‌

It‌‌is‌‌therefore‌‌interesting,‌‌for‌‌any‌‌firm,‌‌to‌‌try‌‌and‌‌achieve‌‌a‌‌certain‌‌level‌‌of‌‌market‌‌power.‌ ‌
In‌‌a‌‌perfect‌‌competition,‌‌economic‌‌profit‌‌is‌‌by‌‌no‌‌means‌‌possible‌u ‌ nless‌‌‌in‌‌the‌‌short‌‌run.‌ ‌
















,PART‌‌TWO‌ ‌

In‌‌this‌‌course,‌‌we‌‌adapt‌‌a‌n ‌ eoclassical‌‌approach‌‌‌in‌‌which‌‌a‌‌firm‌‌is‌‌solely‌‌envisioned‌‌as‌‌a‌‌production‌‌
unit:‌‌the‌‌firm‌‌transforms‌‌inputs‌‌into‌‌outputs:‌ ‌
→‌g ‌ oal‌:‌‌maximize‌‌profits‌‌and‌‌hence‌‌minimize‌‌the‌‌production‌‌costs‌‌ ‌

COST‌‌RELATIONSHIPS‌ ‌
A‌‌firm‌‌is‌‌characterised‌‌by‌‌a‌p ‌ roduction‌‌function‌‌‌for‌‌a‌‌single‌‌product‌‌q.‌‌This‌‌function‌‌specifies‌‌the‌‌quantity‌‌
q‌‌that‌‌the‌‌firm‌‌produced‌‌from‌‌using‌‌k‌‌different‌‌inputs:‌‌q = f (x1 , x2 , ..., xk ) ‌

The‌‌relationship‌‌between‌‌the‌‌output‌‌choice‌‌(production‌‌function)‌‌and‌‌the‌‌production‌‌costs‌‌is‌‌expressed‌‌
using‌‌the‌c‌ ost‌‌function‌:‌‌C (q) + F ‌.‌‌As‌‌we‌‌are‌‌looking‌‌to‌‌maximize‌‌profits,‌‌we‌‌will‌‌solve:‌ ‌
k
M inimize ∑ wi xi ‌s.t. f (x1 , x2 , ..., xk ) = Q ‌‌with‌‌Q‌‌=‌‌the‌‌chosen‌‌production‌‌level‌ ‌
i=1
solving‌‌this‌‌linear‌‌problem‌‌for‌a
‌ ll‌‌‌quantity‌‌levels,‌‌results‌‌in‌‌the‌‌optimal‌‌cost‌‌function‌ ‌
where‌‌costs‌‌are‌‌minimized.‌ ‌

There‌‌are‌‌4‌‌categories‌‌of‌‌costs:‌ ‌
1. Fixed‌‌costs‌:‌‌a‌‌given‌‌amount‌‌of‌‌expenditure‌‌that‌‌the‌‌firm‌‌must‌‌incur‌e ‌ ach‌‌p
‌ eriod‌‌‌and‌‌that‌‌is‌‌
unrelated‌‌‌to‌‌how‌‌much‌‌output‌‌the‌‌firm‌‌produces.‌ ‌

2. Average‌‌costs‌:‌‌the‌‌total‌‌costs‌‌divided‌‌by‌‌output:‌ ‌
- Average F ixed Costs : F /Q ‌
- Average V ariable Costs : C(Q)/Q ‌

3. Marginal‌‌costs‌:‌‌the‌‌addition‌‌to‌‌total‌‌costs‌‌that‌‌is‌‌incurred‌‌in‌‌increasing‌‌output‌‌by‌‌one‌‌unit‌ ‌
→‌‌M arginal Costs : dC(Q)/dQ ‌

4. Sunk‌‌costs‌:‌‌costs‌‌that‌‌are‌‌also‌u ‌ nrelated‌‌‌to‌‌the‌‌output,‌‌but‌‌that‌‌are‌‌spent‌‌before‌‌measuring‌‌the‌‌
total‌‌costs‌‌(e.g.‌‌licences,‌‌research‌‌expenditures,...)‌‌and‌‌are‌‌also‌u ‌ nrecoverable‌‌‌if‌‌the‌‌firm‌‌
decides‌‌to‌‌exit‌‌the‌‌market.‌ ‌

COST‌‌VARIABLES‌‌AND‌‌OUTPUT‌‌DECISIONS‌‌ ‌
Profit‌‌maximization‌‌over‌‌any‌‌period‌‌of‌‌time‌‌requires‌‌that‌‌the‌‌produced‌‌where‌M ‌ C‌‌=‌‌MR‌.‌ ‌
But‌‌‌it‌‌is‌‌important‌‌to‌‌note‌‌that‌‌this‌‌is‌‌only‌‌applicable‌i‌f‌‌the‌‌company‌‌produces‌.‌ ‌

A‌‌company‌‌can‌‌produce‌‌in‌‌its‌‌equilibrium‌‌but‌‌the‌‌total‌‌revenue‌‌could‌‌be‌‌smaller‌‌than‌‌the‌‌
total‌‌costs.‌‌This‌‌happens‌‌when‌‌the‌‌equilibrium‌‌is‌‌under‌‌the‌‌AVC-curve.‌ ‌
→‌‌in‌‌this‌‌case,‌‌the‌‌firm‌‌would‌‌not‌‌produce‌‌and‌‌leave‌‌the‌‌market‌‌=‌s‌ hut-down‌‌decision‌ ‌

In‌‌short,‌‌output‌‌decisions‌‌are‌‌based‌‌on:‌ ‌
1. Marginal‌‌Costs‌ ‌
→‌‌to‌‌decide‌h ‌ ow‌‌much‌‌‌to‌‌produce:‌‌MC‌‌=‌‌MR‌ ‌
2. Average‌‌Costs‌ ‌
→‌‌to‌‌decide‌‌if‌‌the‌‌firm‌‌will‌‌even‌‌produce‌‌in‌‌the‌l‌ong‌‌run‌ ‌
(losses‌‌in‌‌the‌‌SR‌‌are‌‌tolerated,‌n ‌ ot‌‌‌in‌‌the‌‌long‌‌run)‌ ‌
3. Average‌‌Variable‌‌Costs‌‌ ‌
→‌‌to‌‌decide‌‌if‌‌the‌‌firm‌‌will‌‌even‌‌produce‌‌in‌‌the‌s ‌ hort‌‌run‌ ‌
(price‌‌<‌‌AC‌‌can‌‌be‌‌tolerated,‌‌price‌‌<‌‌AVC‌n ‌ ot‌‌‌because‌‌then‌‌every‌‌unit‌‌is‌‌a‌‌loss)‌ ‌


ECONOMIES‌‌OF‌‌SCALE‌‌ ‌
The‌‌state‌‌of‌‌affairs‌‌in‌‌which‌‌average‌‌costs‌‌fall‌‌as‌‌output‌‌increases,‌‌meaning‌‌that‌‌the‌‌cost‌‌per‌‌unit‌‌of‌‌
output‌‌declines‌‌as‌‌the‌‌scale‌‌of‌‌operations‌‌rises.‌ ‌

→‌f‌alling‌‌AC-curve‌‌ ‌ ‌MC‌‌<‌‌AC‌ ‌

AC(Q)
We‌‌define‌‌S = M C(Q) ‌
- ⇒
if‌‌S‌‌>‌‌1‌‌ ‌‌economies‌‌of‌‌scale‌ ‌
- ⇒
if‌‌S‌‌=‌‌1‌‌ ‌m‌ inimum‌‌efficient‌‌scale‌‌
- ⇒
if‌‌S‌‌<‌‌1‌‌ ‌‌diseconomies‌‌of‌‌scale‌ ‌

,We‌‌conclude‌‌that‌‌the‌‌greater‌‌the‌‌extent‌‌of‌‌economies‌‌of‌‌scale,‌‌the‌‌larger‌‌the‌‌output‌‌at‌‌which‌‌the‌‌average‌‌
cost‌‌is‌‌minimized,‌‌the‌‌fewer‌‌firms‌‌that‌‌can‌‌operate‌‌efficiently‌‌in‌‌the‌‌market‌ ‌
⇒ ‌l‌arger‌‌economies‌‌of‌‌scale‌‌for‌‌a‌‌few‌‌firms‌‌will‌‌result‌‌in‌‌concentrated‌‌markets‌ ‌

Now,‌‌what‌‌causes‌‌economies‌‌of‌‌scale?‌ ‌
- underlying‌‌technology‌ ‌

- greater‌‌scale‌‌of‌‌operations‌‌ ‌‌specialization‌‌and‌‌division‌‌of‌‌labor‌ ‌
- economies‌‌on‌‌inventory,‌‌repair,...‌ ‌
- capacity‌‌related‌‌solutions‌‌(e.g.‌‌volume‌‌of‌‌container‌‌that‌‌increases‌‌exponentially)‌ ‌

ECONOMIES‌‌OF‌‌SCOPE‌ ‌
The‌‌state‌‌of‌‌affairs‌‌in‌‌which‌‌it‌‌is‌‌less‌‌costly‌‌to‌‌produce‌‌a‌‌set‌‌of‌‌goods‌‌in‌‌one‌‌firm‌‌than‌‌it‌‌is‌‌to‌‌produce‌‌that‌‌
set‌‌in‌‌two‌‌or‌‌more‌‌firms.‌ ‌

We‌‌define‌‌S C =

C(q 1 , 0) + F 1 + C(0, q 2 ) + F [C(q 1 , q 2 ) + F ]

C(q 1 , q 2 ) + F

- ⇒
if‌‌S‌‌>‌‌0‌‌ ‌‌economies‌‌of‌‌scope‌ ‌
- ⇒
if‌‌S‌‌=‌‌0‌‌ ‌‌critical‌‌point,‌‌indifference‌ ‌
- ⇒
if‌‌S‌‌<‌‌0‌‌ ‌‌no‌‌economies‌‌of‌‌scope‌ ‌

The‌‌concept‌‌of‌‌economies‌‌of‌‌scope‌‌is‌‌an‌‌important‌‌one,‌‌as‌‌it‌‌provides‌‌the‌‌central‌‌technological‌‌reason‌‌
for‌‌the‌‌existence‌‌of‌‌multiproduct‌‌firms.‌‌There‌‌are‌‌two‌‌causes‌‌for‌‌economies‌‌of‌‌scope:‌ ‌
1. Shared‌‌inputs‌ ‌
→‌‌e.g.‌‌shared‌‌R&D,‌‌equipment‌‌that‌‌can‌‌be‌‌used‌‌for‌‌multiple‌‌products,...‌ ‌

2. Cost‌‌complementarities‌‌ ‌
→‌‌producing‌‌one‌‌good‌‌reduces‌‌the‌‌cost‌‌of‌‌another‌ ‌

MARKET‌‌STRUCTURE‌‌ ‌
The‌M ‌ arket‌‌Structure‌‌i‌s‌‌defined‌‌as‌‌the‌‌amount‌‌and‌‌size‌‌of‌‌firms‌‌within‌‌that‌‌market‌‌+‌‌other‌‌factors.‌ ‌
How‌‌to‌‌measure‌‌the‌‌market‌‌structure?‌‌ ‌
- summary‌‌measures‌‌(e.g.‌‌number‌‌of‌‌firms,‌‌market‌‌share‌‌of‌‌each‌‌firm,...)‌ ‌
- concentration‌‌curve‌ ‌
- concentration‌‌ratios‌‌(e.g.‌‌C Rn )‌ ‌
- Herfindahl-Hirschman‌‌Index‌‌(HII)‌ ‌

Summary‌‌measures‌ ‌

Most‌‌of‌‌the‌‌times‌‌fairly‌i‌n‌accurate‌‌as‌‌is‌‌hard‌‌to‌‌list‌‌all‌‌competitors‌‌within‌‌one‌‌
market.‌ ‌



Concentration‌‌Curve‌‌ ‌

How‌‌large‌‌are‌‌the‌‌largest‌‌firms?‌‌→‌‌cfr.‌‌steepness‌‌of‌‌curve‌ ‌
How‌‌quickly‌‌do‌‌we‌‌reach‌‌100%?‌ ‌
…‌ ‌




Concentration‌‌Ratios‌ ‌
e.g.‌‌C R4 =‌‌ratio‌‌that‌‌tells‌‌you‌‌how‌‌much‌‌market‌‌share‌‌the‌‌4‌‌largest‌‌firms‌‌in‌‌a‌‌market‌‌have‌‌combined.‌ ‌

Herfindahl-Hirschman‌‌Index‌‌(HHI)‌ ‌
N
H HI = ∑ si2 ‌‌=‌‌sum‌‌of‌s
‌ quared‌m
‌ arket‌‌shares‌‌of‌‌each‌‌company.‌ ‌
i=1


, MARKET‌‌DEFINITION‌ ‌
We‌‌understand‌‌that‌‌it‌‌is‌‌impossible‌‌to‌‌calculate‌‌metrics‌‌on‌‌the‌‌market‌‌structure,‌‌if‌‌we‌‌have‌‌no‌‌clear‌‌
definition‌‌of‌‌the‌‌market‌‌we‌‌are‌‌studying.‌‌But‌‌defining‌‌a‌‌market‌‌is‌‌no‌‌easy‌‌thing‌‌to‌‌do:‌ ‌

1. define‌‌by‌‌substitutability‌‌in‌p ‌ roduction‌ ‌
→‌‌standard‌‌approach,‌‌based‌‌on‌‌industry‌‌codes‌‌ ‌
→‌‌but‌‌limitations‌ ‌

2. define‌‌by‌‌substitutability‌‌in‌c ‌ onsumption‌‌ ‌
→‌‌=‌d ‌ emand‌‌substitutability‌‌ ‌
→‌‌based‌‌on‌‌cross-price‌‌elasticity‌‌ ‌

We‌‌should‌‌also‌‌ask‌‌ourselves:‌w ‌ hat‌‌drives‌‌potential‌‌market‌‌concentration?‌‌ ‌
a. economies‌‌of‌‌scale‌‌/‌‌economies‌‌of‌‌scope‌ ‌
→‌‌larger‌‌firms‌‌become‌‌more‌‌efficient,‌‌concentration‌‌rises‌ ‌

b. network‌‌externalities‌ ‌
→‌‌concentrated,‌‌even‌‌though‌‌there‌‌could‌‌be‌‌no‌‌economies‌‌of‌‌scale‌‌/‌‌scope‌ ‌

c. government‌‌and‌‌antitrust‌‌policy‌ ‌
→‌‌by‌‌limiting‌‌entry,‌‌patent‌‌system,‌‌blocking‌‌of‌‌mergers,...‌ ‌


PART‌‌THREE‌ ‌

THE‌‌CONCEPT‌‌OF‌‌DISCOUNTING‌ ‌
Both‌‌the‌‌competition‌‌and‌‌monopoly‌‌models‌‌are‌‌somewhat‌‌vague‌‌with‌‌respect‌‌to‌‌time.‌ ‌
As‌‌we‌‌know‌‌money‌‌has‌‌a‌‌time‌‌value,‌‌the‌‌meaning‌‌of‌‌profit‌‌or‌‌break-even‌‌is‌‌less‌‌clear.‌ ‌
→‌‌we‌‌need‌‌a‌‌way‌‌to‌‌convert‌‌tomorrow's‌‌money‌‌into‌‌today's‌‌money‌ ‌
⇒ ‌‌we‌‌will‌‌make‌‌use‌‌of‌‌discounting‌‌and‌‌Net‌‌Present‌‌Value‌ ‌

(Net)‌‌Present‌‌Value‌‌is‌‌directly‌‌relevant‌‌to‌‌profit‌‌maximization:‌ ‌
- for‌o ‌ ne-period‌p ‌ roblems,‌‌we‌‌just‌‌continue‌‌to‌‌use‌‌the‌M‌ R‌‌=‌‌MC‌‌‌optimality‌‌constraint‌ ‌

- for‌m ‌ ultiperiod‌p ‌ roblems,‌‌we‌‌need‌‌to‌‌make‌‌sure‌‌that‌‌the‌‌present‌‌value‌‌of‌‌future‌‌income‌‌streams‌‌
must‌‌at‌‌least‌‌cover‌‌the‌‌present‌‌value‌‌of‌‌the‌‌expenses‌‌in‌‌establishing‌‌the‌‌project:‌P ‌ V‌‌-‌‌I‌‌>‌‌0‌‌ ‌

EFFICIENCY‌‌AND‌‌SURPLUS‌ ‌
Why‌‌are‌‌monopolies‌‌often‌‌blocked?‌‌ ‌
→‌r‌ eason‌:‌‌monopolies‌‌are‌i‌n‌efficient.‌ ‌

Efficiency‌:‌a ‌ ‌‌market‌‌outcome‌‌is‌‌efficient‌‌when‌‌it‌‌is‌‌impossible‌‌to‌‌find‌‌a‌‌small‌‌change‌‌in‌‌the‌‌allocation‌‌of‌‌
capital,‌‌labor,‌‌goods‌‌or‌‌services‌‌that‌‌would‌‌improve‌‌the‌‌well-being‌‌of‌‌individuals‌‌without‌‌hurting‌‌others.‌‌ ‌
→‌‌an‌‌analysis‌‌of‌‌surpluses‌‌will‌‌give‌‌us‌‌an‌‌idea‌‌of‌‌why‌‌a‌‌monopoly‌‌is‌‌inefficient‌‌and‌‌thus‌‌unwanted‌ ‌

PERFECT‌‌COMPETITION‌ ‌
Efficiency‌‌is‌‌basically‌‌a‌‌measure‌‌of‌‌well-being.‌ ‌
a. Consumer‌‌surplus‌:‌t‌he‌‌difference‌‌between‌‌the‌‌maximum‌‌amount‌‌a‌‌consumer‌‌is‌‌

willing‌‌to‌‌pay,‌‌and‌‌the‌‌amount‌‌actually‌‌paid‌‌ ‌C ‌ S‌‌‌(aggregated)‌ ‌

b. Producer‌‌surplus‌:‌t‌he‌‌difference‌‌between‌‌the‌‌amount‌‌a‌‌producer‌‌receives‌‌from‌‌a‌‌

sale‌‌and‌‌the‌‌amount‌‌that‌‌the‌‌sale‌‌cost‌‌him‌‌ ‌P ‌ S‌‌‌(aggregated)‌ ‌

In‌‌this‌‌diagram‌‌(perfect‌‌competition),‌‌we‌‌can‌‌see‌‌that‌‌both‌‌surpluses‌‌are‌‌maximized.‌ ‌
→‌‌the‌‌competitive‌‌equilibrium‌‌is‌e ‌ fficient‌‌‌and‌‌welfare‌‌is‌‌maximized‌




Voordelen van het kopen van samenvattingen bij Stuvia op een rij:

√  	Verzekerd van kwaliteit door reviews

√ Verzekerd van kwaliteit door reviews

Stuvia-klanten hebben meer dan 700.000 samenvattingen beoordeeld. Zo weet je zeker dat je de beste documenten koopt!

Snel en makkelijk kopen

Snel en makkelijk kopen

Je betaalt supersnel en eenmalig met iDeal, Bancontact of creditcard voor de samenvatting. Zonder lidmaatschap.

Focus op de essentie

Focus op de essentie

Samenvattingen worden geschreven voor en door anderen. Daarom zijn de samenvattingen altijd betrouwbaar en actueel. Zo kom je snel tot de kern!

Veelgestelde vragen

Wat krijg ik als ik dit document koop?

Je krijgt een PDF, die direct beschikbaar is na je aankoop. Het gekochte document is altijd, overal en oneindig toegankelijk via je profiel.

Tevredenheidsgarantie: hoe werkt dat?

Onze tevredenheidsgarantie zorgt ervoor dat je altijd een studiedocument vindt dat goed bij je past. Je vult een formulier in en onze klantenservice regelt de rest.

Van wie koop ik deze samenvatting?

Stuvia is een marktplaats, je koop dit document dus niet van ons, maar van verkoper simkuhn. Stuvia faciliteert de betaling aan de verkoper.

Zit ik meteen vast aan een abonnement?

Nee, je koopt alleen deze samenvatting voor €8,00. Je zit daarna nergens aan vast.

Is Stuvia te vertrouwen?

4,6 sterren op Google & Trustpilot (+1000 reviews)

Afgelopen 30 dagen zijn er 82871 samenvattingen verkocht

Opgericht in 2010, al 14 jaar dé plek om samenvattingen te kopen

Start met verkopen
€8,00  86x  verkocht
  • (10)
  Kopen