100% tevredenheidsgarantie Direct beschikbaar na betaling Zowel online als in PDF Je zit nergens aan vast
logo-home
Summary all mandatory articles Foreign Market Entry Strategies €8,99   In winkelwagen

Samenvatting

Summary all mandatory articles Foreign Market Entry Strategies

 15 keer bekeken  2 keer verkocht

Summary of 30 pages for the course Foreign Market Entry Strategies at RuG (-)

Voorbeeld 3 van de 30  pagina's

  • 11 januari 2024
  • 30
  • 2023/2024
  • Samenvatting
Alle documenten voor dit vak (1)
avatar-seller
vdeliege
Summary Foreign Market Entry Strategies
Year: 2023 – 2024


W1: Course outline and Introduction to Foreign entry strategies
◦ Anderson, E., & Gatignon, H. 1986. Modes of foreign entry: A transaction cost analysis and
propositions. Journal of International Business Studies, 17(3), 1–26.
◦ Hennart, J.-F.2009 Down with MNE-centric theories! Market entry and expansion as the
bundling of MNE and local assets. Journal of International Business Studies, 40(9), 1432–1454.

W2: Traditional and not traditional entry modes
◦ 1. Brouthers, K. D., Chen, L., Li, S., & Shaheer, N. (2022). Charting new courses to enter foreign
markets: Conceptualization, theoretical framework, and research directions on non-traditional
entry modes. Journal of International Business Studies, 53(9), 2088-2115.
◦ 2. Dikova, D., & Van Witteloostuijn, A. (2007). Foreign direct investment mode choice: entry
and establishment modes in transition economies. Journal of International Business Studies,
38(6), 1013–1033
◦ 3. Chen, S.-F. S. (2008). The motives for international acquisitions: Capability procurements,
strategic considerations, and the role of ownership structures. Journal of International Business
Studies, 39(3), 454–471.

W3: Corporate governance: Shareholders type
◦ 1. Yamanoi, J., & Asaba, S. (2018). The impact of family ownership on establishment and
ownership modes in foreign direct investment: The moderating role of corruption in host
countries. Global Strategy Journal, 8(1): 106–135.
◦ 2. Grøgaard, B., Rygh, A., & Benito, G. R. (2019). Bringing corporate governance into
internalization theory: State ownership and foreign entry strategies. Journal of International
Business Studies, 50, 1310-1337.

W4: International alliance portfolios
◦ 1. Lavie, D., & Miller, S. R. (2008). Alliance portfolio internationalization and firm performance.
Organisation science, 19(4), 623-646.
◦ 2. Bos, B., Faems, D., & Noseleit, F. (2017). Alliance Concentration in Multinational Companies:
Examining Alliance Portfolios, Firm Structure, and Firm Performance. Strategic Management
Journal, 38(11), 2298-2309.

W5: International Joint Ventures: performance, stability and evolution
◦ 1. Luo, Y., & Park, S. H. (2004). Multiparty cooperation and performance in international equity
joint ventures. Journal of International Business Studies, 35(2), 142–160.
◦ 2. Yan, A. (1998). Structural stability and reconfiguration of international joint ventures. Journal
of International Business Studies, 29(4), 773– 796.

W6: Post-entry strategies – Re-entry strategies
◦ 1. Chang, S.-J., Chung, J., & Moon, J. J. (2013). When do wholly-owned subsidiaries perform
better than joint ventures? Strategic Management Journal, 34(3), 317–337.
◦ 2. Surdu, I., Mellahi, K., & Glaister, K. W. (2019). Once bitten, not necessarily shy? Determinants
of foreign market re-entry commitment strategies. Journal of International Business Studies,
50(3), 393–422.
◦ 3. Brouthers, K. D. (2002). Institutional, cultural and transaction cost influences on entry mode
choice and performance. Journal of International Business Studies, 33(2), 203-221.

,W1: Course outline and Introduction to Foreign entry strategies

Anderson, E., & Gatignon, H. 1986. Modes of foreign entry: A transaction cost analysis and propositions.
Journal of International Business Studies, 17(3), 1–26.

Abstract
A "frontier issue" in international marketing is the appropriate choice of entry mode in foreign markets.
The objective of this paper is to offer a transaction cost framework for investigating the entry mode
decision. This framework provides: 1) a theoretical basis for systematically interrelating the literature
into propositions; 2) propositions about interactions which resolve the apparently contradictory
arguments advanced to date. Specifically, the paper:
• illustrates the feasibility of clustering 17 entry modes into the degree of control the
mode provides the entrant;
• proposes that the most appropriate (i.e., most efficient) entry- mode is a function of
the tradeoff between control & the cost of resource commitment.
• advances testable propositions delimiting the circumstances under which each mode
maximizes long-term efficiency.
The entry mode literature is reviewed in the context of these propositions, and guidelines are derived
for choosing the appropriate mode of entry, given certain characteristics of the firm, the product, and
the environment.

‘Mode of entry’ (order from high control to low control):
- Wholly owned subsidiary (WOS)
- Joint venture (JVs). Entrant is:
o Majority-;
o Equal-;
o Or minority partner.
- Nonequity arrangement, such as licensing or a contractual JV.

Control (= ability to influence systems, methods, and decisions) has a critical impact on the future of a
foreign enterprise:
- High-control modes can increase return and risk.
- Low-control modes (e.g., licenses and other contractual agreements) minimize resource
commitment (hence risk) but often at the expense of returns.
→ Tradeoff between control & cost of resource commitments, often under conditions of considerable
risk and uncertainty (versus maintaining flexibility).
→ Commitment of resources includes high overhead which in turn creates switching costs, reducing
the firm's ability to change its institutional arrangement should its choice turn out to be suboptimal.

In certain nonequity modes, moderate control comes from daily involvement in the operation and from
expertise. These modes include:
- Contract management
- Contractual joint ventures
- Restrictive exclusive contracts
- Franchising (form of licensing in which the use of a business system is granted)
- Contracts that are exclusive but nonrestrictive or nonexclusive but restrictive

Figure 1 is a progression from complete non-integration (classical marketing contracting between two
parties) to complete integration (one entity "contracts" internally to perform a function), passing
through intermediate points.

, The efficiency of an entry mode depends on 4 constructs that determine the optimal degree of control,
following a transaction-cost analysis:
1. Transaction-specific assets: investments (physical & human) that are specialized to one or a
few users or uses;
2. External uncertainty: the unpredictability of the entrant's external environment;
3. Internal uncertainty: the entrant's inability to determine its agents' performance by observing
output measures;
4. Free-riding potential: agents' ability to receive benefits without bearing the associated costs.




Transaction-specific assets
Transaction cost analysis approaches the entry mode question with the following promise: a low level
of ownership is preferable until proven otherwise (= default hypothesis).
Integration (or direct investment) is justified when the market mechanism no longer encourages
performance, i.e., when competitive pressure is low.
Degeneration into lock in occurs when "transaction-specific assets" of considerable value accumulate.
These are investments (physical & human) that are valuable only in a narrow range of transactions, that
is, specialized to one or a few users or uses.

Transaction-specific assets:
Proposition 1: “Modes of entry offering greater control are more efficient for highly proprietary
products or processes.”
Proprietary knowledge, a type of specialized asset, is subject to hazards of transmission and valuation.
It is often ill-codified and difficult to transmit across organizational boundaries. Firms with proprietary
knowledge tend to exert more control to avoid risks associated with licensing out this knowledge.

Proposition 2: “Entry modes offering higher degrees of control are more efficient for unstructured,
poorly-understood products and processes.”
For products and processes that are ill-structured or poorly understood, high-control entry modes are
preferable. This is because the development of a common code of understanding, which is critical for
such functions, is better preserved and extended in high-control modes.

Voordelen van het kopen van samenvattingen bij Stuvia op een rij:

Verzekerd van kwaliteit door reviews

Verzekerd van kwaliteit door reviews

Stuvia-klanten hebben meer dan 700.000 samenvattingen beoordeeld. Zo weet je zeker dat je de beste documenten koopt!

Snel en makkelijk kopen

Snel en makkelijk kopen

Je betaalt supersnel en eenmalig met iDeal, creditcard of Stuvia-tegoed voor de samenvatting. Zonder lidmaatschap.

Focus op de essentie

Focus op de essentie

Samenvattingen worden geschreven voor en door anderen. Daarom zijn de samenvattingen altijd betrouwbaar en actueel. Zo kom je snel tot de kern!

Veelgestelde vragen

Wat krijg ik als ik dit document koop?

Je krijgt een PDF, die direct beschikbaar is na je aankoop. Het gekochte document is altijd, overal en oneindig toegankelijk via je profiel.

Tevredenheidsgarantie: hoe werkt dat?

Onze tevredenheidsgarantie zorgt ervoor dat je altijd een studiedocument vindt dat goed bij je past. Je vult een formulier in en onze klantenservice regelt de rest.

Van wie koop ik deze samenvatting?

Stuvia is een marktplaats, je koop dit document dus niet van ons, maar van verkoper vdeliege. Stuvia faciliteert de betaling aan de verkoper.

Zit ik meteen vast aan een abonnement?

Nee, je koopt alleen deze samenvatting voor €8,99. Je zit daarna nergens aan vast.

Is Stuvia te vertrouwen?

4,6 sterren op Google & Trustpilot (+1000 reviews)

Afgelopen 30 dagen zijn er 75632 samenvattingen verkocht

Opgericht in 2010, al 14 jaar dé plek om samenvattingen te kopen

Start met verkopen
€8,99  2x  verkocht
  • (0)
  Kopen